Many people seem to sympathize with members of abstract
groupings such as ‘The Poor’ and ‘The Workers’. This sympathy leads them to
applaud policies that are perceived to benefit ‘The Poor’ or ‘The Workers’, or
other favoured groups, while condemning policies that are perceived to harm
members of these groups.
While I too sympathize with people who don’t have many
material resources and with people who work hard for a living, I also
sympathize with some other abstract groups of individuals, groups who not many
others seem to sympathize with. These groups include: The Taxpayers, The
Victims of Purchasing-Power Drainage, and The Restricted. The interests of members
of these groups are often harmed by interventionist, statist policies that seem
to be beneficial to The Poor and The Workers. As a result, my sympathies for
members of these three groups often lead me to be more critical of such
policies than others.
1. The Taxpayers
I have relatively strong feelings of sympathy for people who
do nice things for me. It makes me happy when good things happen to such
people, unhappy when bad things happen to such people. I think that this trait
is fairly common among humans. It gives rise to the popular sentiments of
Gratitude and Loyalty.
I know that as a consumer, my standard of living is based on
the actions of the producers. The more they produce, the more the money I earn
will enable me to consume. It is true that not every producer contributes
directly to producing the products that I seek to buy. However, I know that the
market system cannot just cater to my demands alone. In order for it to
function, it must cater to the demands of all consumers with purchasing power.
Hence, in this instance, I tether my interests to those of consumers in
general. Whenever a producer earns a high income by producing things that the
consumers want, the system of production for the consumers is advanced. The more
this system is advanced, the better off I will be as a consumer. Hence, when I
see a producer earning a high income through free-market means, I consider them
to be a benefactor, and thus I particularly sympathize with them.
The reason why ‘welfare State’ policies are popular is
because their supposed purpose is to ‘help the poor with the money of the rich’.
As I’ve argued elsewhere, often these policies are highly overrated as means of
benefitting the poor. However, many advocates of ‘welfare State’ policies
sympathize so much more with The Poor than they do with the richer Taxpayers
that pointing this out does little to dissuade them from their advocacy.
People like me who believe that free-market economic theory
is correct and who have a penchant for gratitude-based sympathy will take the
interests of the richer Taxpayers far more into account than your typical ‘welfare
State’ supporter will. While most of us will also sympathize with The Poor, when
it comes to evaluating ‘welfare State’ policies, our sympathy for the richer
Taxpayers will lead to more balanced out sympathetic considerations than those
of your typical leftist. This, combined with our doubts about the effectiveness
of ‘welfare State’ policies as means of helping The Poor, and our greater trust
in voluntary action to help The Poor, usually leads us to oppose these kinds of
policies.
2. The Victims of
Purchasing-Power Drainage
Producers who produce what the consumers want are rewarded
with purchasing-power, which they can then use as consumers themselves. This
earned purchasing-power can be taken away from these people in two ways: the
first is via confiscation of earned currency units, or taxation, which we
considered above. The second is via the drainage of the purchasing-power of
those earned currency units. The gratitude-based sympathy for The Taxpayer that
I have thus also extends to The Victim of Purchasing-Power Drainage.
Purchasing-power can be purposefully drained in two ways: via
inflation or via restrictions on production and exchange.
Inflation: When the government (or a private counterfeiter)
prints/creates more units of currency, the greater supply of currency, other
things equal, will eventually act to reduce the purchasing-power of every unit
of currency. This does not happen right away though; first the newly-created
currency must flow throughout the economy. It starts this flow from the pockets
of the government’s central bank/the private counterfeiter, then moves on to
the people they buy from, which then moves on to the people that these people
buy from, and so on. The earlier on in this flow you are situated, the better
off, as when you receive the benefits of the new money, it is more likely that
the new money has not yet raised the price of the things that you want to buy.
If you are situated relatively late in this flow, or if you have missed it
entirely because you have a fixed income, it is more likely that you will receive
the benefit, if at all, only after the new money has raised the price of the
things that you want to buy. These people are the ones whose purchasing-power
is drained by the inflationary policies.
Restrictions on production and exchange: Whenever government policies make it more difficult for producers
to produce what consumers want to buy or to get the products to the consumer,
the general purchasing-power of the consumer with a given amount of currency will
be relatively impaired. Protectionist tariffs or import quotas, which make it
more difficult for consumers to buy from international sources, are probably
the most obvious example of these kinds of purchasing-power-draining policies.
There are many others though. Policies ranging from professional licensing
requirements, to onerous labor and environmental regulations, to taxation or
other policies that discourage capital formation and investment, all act to
drain the purchasing-power, other things equal, of the currency units of the
consumers.
Advocates of inflationary policies and of policies that
restrict production/exchange usually focus on the benefits accruing to certain
groups as a result of these policies: from the small business owner that can
now get a loan due to the inflationary ‘easy money’, to the domestic producer
who is now ‘protected’ from fierce foreign competition, to the worker whose
working conditions the labor regulations are intended to ‘improve’.
They usually fail to mention the Victims of Purchasing-Power
Drainage that these policies create. Ironically, The Poor and The Workers, the
groups that get so much love when they are supposed to be benefitting from
government interventions, are the groups that are generally the most sensitive
and susceptible to these kinds of purchasing-power drains. Members of these
groups are often situated late in the inflationary flow of money, and they are
more sensitive to losses in purchasing-power because they didn’t have that much
to begin with.
Whether Poor, Worker, or anyone else, I sympathize with all
Victims of Purchasing-Power Drainage. I am grateful to producers for providing
consumers, including myself, with the goods and services that they do, in
exchange for the purchasing-power which we give them in return. When government
policies drain the purchasing-power that these producers earned, I feel
resentment on their behalf, wishing that my benefactors weren’t treated so
shabbily. The fact that these purchasing-power drains are done covertly, a kind
of robbery by stealth, makes it even worse in my eyes.
These sympathetic feelings that I, and people who think like
me on this issue, have, tend to make us more defensive of the interests of the
consumer and the inflation-victim. This makes it more likely that we will
oppose the kinds of purchasing-power-draining policies discussed above.
3. The Restricted
This group is comprised of people whose non-aggressively-violent
freedom of action is restricted coercively, usually by a government. While my
sympathy for the first two groups discussed was based on both understanding
(ability to imagine being in their shoes and experiencing the situation in
question) and gratitude, my sympathy for this group is based solely on
understanding.
I am a free-spirited person and when the government
coercively tells me that I can’t do something that does not involve aggressive
violence, I feel annoyed and resentful. Thus, I can definitely understand the
plight of members of the abstract group, The Restricted, and thus I sympathize
with them. This holds even if the freedom being restricted is one that I myself
would not choose to exercise, such as the freedom to use recreational drugs.
By contrast, many people only sympathize with those whose
particular freedom being restricted is one that they too would choose to
exercise, rather than with The Restricted as an abstract grouping like I, and
other libertarian-leaning people, do. A North American Christian may be
indignant about the freedom to practice Christianity of people in China and the
Middle East being restricted, but may not particularly care about people whose
freedom to practice religions other than Christianity is being restricted. An
American Conservative may bellow indignantly if people’s freedom to keep
firearms is being restricted, and yet join the chorus of people who want to
restrict people’s freedom to ingest the recreational drugs of their choice.
People like me who sympathize with victims of the restriction
of non-aggressively-violent freedom of action in general are more likely to
favor more consistently-libertarian policies than people who only sympathize
with victims of restriction selectively.
Conclusion
Why do only some people sympathize with these three abstract
groups of people while others do not? Is it because our brains are wired
differently from one another? Or is it because one group has thought about the
issues at hand more, or from a different perspective, than the other? I for one
hope that it is the latter; because then there would be hope for a
rapprochement between the two sides. If it’s the former, then we will
unfortunately have to agree to disagree.
No comments:
Post a Comment