Wednesday 1 February 2017

An Empowering Infrastructure System

As promised, this post examines what a maximally-empowering system of infrastructure policy might look like. The basic principle is fairly straightforward: if it can be done by private companies, then it should be done by private companies. Why? Because as we have discussed in many other posts, market-incentivized, competitive private businesses are generally better at giving the consumers what they want than monopolistic, politically-incentivized governments.

So, can private companies indeed be given responsibility for our infrastructure? Big government proponents will respond in the negative, arguing that because infrastructure is a ‘public good’, whose benefits are more difficult to monetize than the ‘private goods’ on the private market, it must be provided by the government, rather than by profit-seeking enterprises. Actually though, the benefits from most infrastructure can be monetized relatively easily, and hence it can be provided by a profit-seeking private business. In this post, I will show how.

Long-distance infrastructure
We begin with long-distance infrastructure, which includes highways, railways, and pipelines. With these, monetization is quite simple: just charge people based on how much of it they use.
What’s a bit more complicated is securing the property necessary to build this kind of infrastructure in the first place. Building this kind of infrastructure requires the builder to have ownership of, or right of way over, a large stretch of contiguous land parcels. Most land owners along the proposed route will be willing to negotiate a mutually advantageous right-of-way deal with the builder, but there is always the chance of a few stubborn holdouts who refuse to make a deal at any price. This small minority could render the builder’s infrastructure plan unfeasible.

What’s to be done? Well, here, the government could usefully intervene a little. If they deem the project to be in the country’s economic interests, they could use their power of eminent domain to force the holdouts to sell rights-of-way to the builder. Because it is a compelled sale, the price should be set at twice the going market rate, in order to compensate the reluctant seller for their loss, and in order to prevent overuse of this provision. While it is true that this would deprive the holdout of a great deal of power over his land holdings, it will most likely be outweighed by the economic benefits (and corresponding increase in general purchasing power), provided by the project.    
This problem aside though, there is really no need for the government to take any other role in the provision of long-distance infrastructure. Private business can do it just fine.

Urban Infrastructure
Now we come to another category of infrastructure: urban infrastructure. This includes roads, sewers, parks, powerlines, neighborhood rules (non-physical infrastructure), garbage collection, etc… Monetizing the benefits from this kind of infrastructure is a little more challenging than it is for the long-distance variety, mainly because it is so intertwined with people’s homes and neighborhoods. But therein lies the key to its monetization: it’s price should be included in the price of a home!
Here’s how it would work. A whole neighborhood (or district) would be owned by a single landlord (or condominium association). The landlord would rent out individual buildings to people, in exchange for a regular monthly payment. The landlord would use part of these payments to maintain the infrastructure of the neighborhood. Why? Because it’s part of the product that he’s selling! The nicer/more functional the neighborhood’s infrastructure, the more the landlord will be able to charge for the privilege of living in that neighborhood. In order for his neighborhood to remain competitive with others, it is in the landlord’s interest to provide the best possible infrastructure for the amount of money that tenants are willing to pay for it.

Some may object that, under this arrangement, the neighborhood landlords are given too much power, while the residents are deprived of the power that comes with independent home ownership. Unfortunately, independent home ownership and city living are incompatible. In the current system, people have the illusion of being independent home owners, but actually, it is more accurate to say that they are in a condominium arrangement. The local municipal government is like a condominium association, which, like such associations, is elected democratically, levies condo fees (property tax), and controls the condo’s (city’s) infrastructure.

In the private neighborhood model, there exists the option of organizing the neighborhood on a condominium basis, where residents have limited ownership of their individual buildings and the infrastructure is maintained by a pseudo-democratic condominium associations, via condo fees that they levy from individual residents. Some people will prefer this arrangement as a way of feeling more in control of their neighborhood, although it is unlikely that condominium associations will be as responsive or attentive to consumer demand as a profit-seeking landlord.

Cross-neighborhood infrastructure
Some kinds of infrastructure (such as sewers, subway tracks, and power systems) will have to go through and service multiple neighborhoods in order to be effective. If these neighborhoods are owned by different landlords though, won’t there be a problem of coordination? Perhaps a little, but it is in the best interests of the landlords to collaborate effectively on these matters. Why? Because just as whole industries compete against whole other industries for the consumer’s dollar, so would cities against other cities. It is often in the interests of the major, competing players in an industry to work together in order to achieve something that will benefit the industry as a whole (such as a specific law or policy change). Similarly, competing, neighborhood landlords in the same city will tend to work together to make the city as a whole more attractive, as doing so is in both of their interests (they can attract tenants from other cities, and then raise their prices due to the extra demand). If collaborating on a sewer, power, or subway system is what is necessary to do so, chances are that such collaboration will be forthcoming.

Power analysis of private infrastructure system
So, private parties can indeed provide all of the infrastructure that governments provide. But is it desirable that they do so? Yes, it is; for a number of reasons.

Firstly, private businesses will provide better and more cost-effective infrastructure than governments. This is because, unlike governments, they are incentivized and competing with one another to do so. This will increase the purchasing-power of just about everyone in society.

Secondly, private businesses will allocate their infrastructure spending based on the anticipated priorities of the consumers, rather than the priorities of the government. Since one has far more sway as a consumer than one does as a political voter, this is a net positive for power levels.

Thirdly, the private neighborhood model for urban infrastructure will offer consumers of residential housing more choice than the municipal government model. Many neighborhood landlords will likely try to tap a niche market by offering up a distinctive ‘neighborhood experience’. There would likely be artist neighborhoods, professional neighborhoods, ethnic neighborhoods, ritzy neighborhoods, religious neighborhoods, child-friendly neighborhoods, more neighborly neighborhoods, etc… Each of these would have their own distinctive sets of rules, aesthetics, types of communal spaces, services, etc…; designed by the landlord to appeal to the distinct target market for that neighborhood.

This contrasts with the municipal government model, where the whole city is under the sway of the one, slow-moving institution. While there are still distinct neighborhoods, the rules and infrastructure choices are not really designed to appeal to specific target markets, or at least not as effectively as they would be in a private system.

Since the private system provides people with more choice, it also provides them with more power. It provides people with a better opportunity to live in the kind of neighborhood that suits their own, individual preferences. It thus provides people with more power over their surrounding environment; one of the most important kinds.

Transition plan
How would one go about transitioning from the current system to the proposed one? The municipal government would just need to slice the city up into reasonably-sized neighborhoods, then establish a condominium arrangement, governed by a standard contract, in each of them. The contract should have a provision, like most existing condominiums, where if some kind of supermajority (usually 75%) agree to sell their interests to a buyer interested in the whole neighborhood, then the holdouts can be forced to sell as well. This would provide a mechanism for converting a neighborhood into a landlord-tenant model, if enough people agreed.

Objection: bad for the poor
An objection that could be raised to this system is that in it, people will have to pay for all of the infrastructure benefits that they receive, rather than in the current system where the government pays for it via taxation and then gives it away for free. This will be especially hard on the poor.

In response, I would say that if private businesses can do something far better than governments can, then they should, even if the government option happened to subsidize the poor. This is because there are more effective ways of subsidizing the poor: just give them some money, and then they too can access the far-superior private system. There’s no sense opting for an inferior system just because of a few poor people: just go with the better system, and then help the poor get what they need from it. And in this case, the private infrastructure system will be much better than the government one; I guarantee it.


No comments:

Post a Comment