23. Ad Hominem attacks do not advance intellectual arguments:
When you are
considering a thinker’s argument, you should always focus your intellectual
energy and critical thinking on the thinker’s ideas instead of on the life or
personality traits of the thinker himself. Even if the thinker happens to be a
serial killer, if he articulated an idea that, considered on its own, seems to
be a very good one, the fact that the thinker is a serial killer should do
nothing to discredit that idea. Of course, one might question how many
brilliant ideas serial killers will come up with, given their day job, but that
is another question entirely.
The intellectuals
most notorious for dedicating themselves to attempting to discredit ideas via
Ad Hominem attacks are the Marxists. Indeed, this has become of the central
tenets of their school of thought. Marxists claim that society is divided into
antagonistic social classes and that for every period of history, one of these
social classes is the dominant one. As the ruling class, they build up a
‘superstructure’ of ideas that legitimises their dominant position in society.
Since economics developed as a separate and sophisticated area of scientific
inquiry in the late 18th and 19th centuries, the era of capitalism dominated by the
‘bourgeois’ or ‘capital-owning’ classes, the economic theories they developed
were automatically considered to be apologies for the dominance of the
‘bourgeois’ classes. By discrediting economists as ‘sycophants of the
bourgeoisie’, Marxists spared themselves the necessity of actually entering
into a serious intellectual critique of these economists’ theories and ideas in
order to make their point. Instead, all economic ideas up to that point, except
those penned by Marx and his followers who of course wrote in the spirit of the
‘working’ classes, were deemed irrelevant by the Marxists because they were
written by members of the bourgeois classes, in the interests of the bourgeois
classes.
Intellectually,
this ploy does not have any merit. The social class backgrounds of all the
great thinkers of history and the ‘interests’ they were supposedly representing
could all be ‘unmasked’, but does that mean that all their ideas are worthless?
The implications are absurd. However, it is true that non-intellectual motives
such as who was patronizing their work, where they stood in their society, etc…
could well have influenced the thinking of these writers. How then do we decide
which of the ideas of these thinkers we should retain and which we should discard?
The answer is: by subjecting them to the test of reason, the test of empirical confirmation,
or both of these tests. In other words, by evaluating the ideas as ideas.
Besides the
Marxists, there are many others who use different variants of the ad hominem
attack strategy. If a white male criticizes affirmative action policies, his
ideas are sometimes disregarded because he is ‘privileged’ and ‘does not understand’ the plight of people whom affirmative action is supposed to help.
It should be clear though that if his whiteness or maleness is impacting his
proper reasoning on this issue, the supporter of affirmative action should be
able to point out the flaws in his reasoning and thus discredit his ideas in
that way. Attacking the thinker is of no avail because either his idea makes
sense or it does not. If it does not, engage in a scientific debate with him.
If it does, then pointing out that the originator of the idea is white or male
does nothing to make it a worse idea. If the disagreement is a valuational one,
then simply explain to him your own valuations of the ends that are pursued
with affirmative action policies and try to bring him around to your way of
thinking.
Another
example is trying to discredit the ideas of a thinker because the thinker is
‘inexperienced’. Perhaps the thinker is younger, or has not been in the business
world for as long, or has not visited as many foreign countries as his
intellectual opponent. Simply pointing out this fact does not constitute an
argument though. In order to make it such, the ‘more experienced’ disputant
should explain how his particular experience serves to refute the argument of
his opponent or supports his own argument. In this way, the one disputant’s
experience serves as just another intellectual weapon in his arsenal of
empirical knowledge on the subject. It definitely does not, though, serve as an
intellectual trump card that confirms that everything the ‘more experienced’
disputant says is true while everything the ‘less experienced’ disputant says
is false.
Ad hominem
attacks are intellectually meaningless and do nothing to advance an argument.
While investigating the biographical details of a thinker may be interesting
for an intellectual historian, such details can never automatically discredit
the ideas of that thinker. Ideas must be combated with other ideas, not with
personal attacks.
24. Old ideas are not necessarily obsolete ideas:
It is a
common myth that new ideas are always better than old ideas. In the natural
sciences, the myth is not as destructive because it is easier to see when a new
idea is an ‘advance’ based on the material manifestations of the idea when the
new theory is applied. Thus, either a new idea can lead to the creation of
telephones or television sets or not, and any layman can see the material
results of such an idea. In the social sciences though, the superiority of some
ideas over others is not as evident to the layman. For one, in the social
sciences, in order for someone to appreciate a new idea as an ‘advance’, they
must understand the idea and the argumentation behind it. As mentioned earlier,
knowledge of just the hard facts of history does not immediately translate into
knowledge of which ideas on social questions were better than others. This is
because history has so many complex, non-isolatable variables operating on it
that it is almost impossible to isolate the social policies pursued by
government as variables and assess these policies based on historical
statistics alone. The layman observer does not need to understand the
complexities of astrophysics in order to understand when an advance in that
field led to the building of a better rocket ship. By contrast, in the social
sciences, the observer must understand the theoretical framework of the science
in question in order to decide for himself when a new idea is an advance or
not.
Secondly, valuational disputes tend
to play a bigger role in the social sciences. Most would agree that the ability
to create safer cars or faster internet connections are good things, but
whether an increase in general economic efficiency at the expense of some
egalitarianism is considered a good thing or not depends on the valuator.
For these reasons, by and large, new
innovations in the natural sciences do, on average at least, tend to represent advances over older
ideas, and thus the myth that new ideas are necessarily
better than old ones is not as destructive in these sciences. In the social
sciences though, because familiarity with the science in question and a fair
amount of critical thinking is necessary in order to determine when a new idea
or policy recommendation is an ‘advance’ or a ‘retrogression’ in the science
and because of more subjectivity in judging social policies and ideas, the myth
is deadly and must be rejected.
For example, a common argument one
hears against returning to a monetary system based on a gold standard goes like
this: ‘The gold standard was the monetary system of the 19th
century. In the 20th century though, every country in the world,
aided by advances in monetary theory, realized that a fiat paper money system
was much more satisfactory. Returning to these outdated, 19th
century monetary ideas in the 21st century is out of the question,
we must advance, not retrogress.’ This is really no argument at all though. A
supporter of the gold standard could argue that while there were many advances
in the 20th century in terms of technology and standard of living,
there was no advance and in fact a retrogression in monetary theory and
monetary systems, accounting for persistent problems of inflation and business
cycles in the 20th and 21st centuries. One does not have
to advocate for a return 19th century transportation techniques
(horse-and-buggies) in order to advocate for a return to 19th
century monetary techniques (the gold standard). It is entirely possible that
while there were advances in transportation technology, there were also
retrogressions in monetary systems and ideas. Though historical periods can only
be compared by taking ‘the whole package’ of economic, social, political, and
technological and comparing that to the ‘whole package’ of another historical
period, the social thinker is, thankfully, under no necessity of either
advocating for one ‘whole package’ or the other. He can pick and choose based
on deductive reasoning, perhaps aided by some empirical studies, and his own
valuations, which policies or ideas represent ‘advances’ and which
‘retrogressions’.
Thus, don’t be afraid to support
‘old’ ideas if you think they are more correct than ‘new’ ideas. In the social
sciences especially, ‘old’ does not necessarily mean ‘obsolete’.
No comments:
Post a Comment